Advanced course « Economics of
Inequality » (Master APE, M2 year)
Thomas Piketty
Année universitaire 2009-2010
Academic year 2009-2010
Course Notes F :
Optimal redistributive taxation of
capital and capital income
T. Piketty, « Income Inequality in
1. Model with capitalists vs
workers: linear capital taxation
Consider
an infinite-horizon, discrete-time economy with a continuum [0;1] of dynasties.
For
simplicity, assume a two-point distribution of wealth. Dynasties can be of one
of two types: either they own a large capital stock ktA,
or they own a low capital stock ktB (ktA >
ktB). The proportion of high-wealth dynasties is
exogenous and equal to λ (and the proportion of low-wealth dynasties is
equal to 1-λ), so that the average capital stock in the economy kt is given by:
kt
= λktA + (1-λ)ktB
Consider first the case
ktB=0. I.e. low-wealth dynasties have zero wealth
(the “workers”) and therefore zero capital income. Their only income is labor
income, and we assume it is so low that they consume it all (zero savings).
High-wealth dynasties are the only dynasties to own wealth and to save. Assume
they maximize a standard dynastic utility function:
Ut =
∑t≥0 U(ct)/(1+θ)t
(U’(c)>0,
U’’(c)<0)
All
dynasties supply exactly one unit of (homogeneous) labor each period. Output
per labor unit is given by a standard production function f(kt)
(f’(k)>0, f’’(k)<0), where kt is the average capital stock per
capita of the economy at period t. Markets for labor and capital are assumed to
be fully competitive, so that the interest rate rt and wage rate vt
are always equal to the marginal products of capital and labor:
rt =
f’(kt)
vt =
f(kt) - rtkt
In such a
dynastic capital accumulation model, it is well-known that the long-run
steady-state interest rate r* and the long-run average capital stock k* are uniquely
determined by the utility function and the technology (irrespective of initial
conditions): in stead-state, r* is necessarily equal to θ, and k* must be
such that:
f’(k*)=r*=θ
I.e.
f’(λkA)=r*=θ
This
result comes directly from the first-order condition:
U’(ct)/
U’(ct+1) = (1+rt)/(1+θ)
I.e. if
the interest rate rt is above the rate of time preference θ, then
agents choose to accumulate capital and to postpone their consumption
indefinitely (ct<ct+1<ct+2<…)
and this cannot be a steady-state. Conversely, if the interest rate rt is below
the rate of time preference θ, agents choose to desaccumulate capital (i.e. to borrow)
indefinitely and to consume more today (ct>ct+1>ct+2>…).
This cannot be a steady-state either.
Now assume we introduce linear redistributive
capital taxation into this model. That is, capital income rtkt
of the capitalists is taxed at tax rate τ (so that the post-tax
capital income of the capitalists becomes (1-τ)rtkt),
and the tax revenues are used to finance a wage subsidy st
(so that the post-transfer labor income of the workers becomes vt+st).
Note kτ* , kAτ*=
kτ*/λ and rτ*
the resulting steady-state capital stock and pre-tax interest rate. The Golden
rule of capital accumulation implies that:
(1- τ) f’(kτ*)=
(1-τ) rτ* = θ
I.e. the
capitalists choose to desaccumulate capital until the point where the net
interest rate is back to its initial level (i.e. the rate of time preference). In effect, the long-run elasticity of
capital supply is infinite in the infinite-horizon model: any infinitesimal
change in the net interest rate generates a savings response that is
unsustainable in the long run, unless the net interest rate returns to its
initial level.
The long
run income of the workers yτ* will be equal to:
yτ*
= vτ* + sτ*
with: vτ* = f(kτ*)
- rτ* kτ*
and: sτ* = τ rτ*
kτ*
That is:
yτ*
= f(kτ*) – (1-τ) rτ* kτ* =
f(kτ*) – θkτ*
Question: what is the capital tax rate τ
maximizing workers’ income yτ* = f(kτ*) –
θkτ* ?
Answer: τ must be such that f’(kτ*)
= θ, i.e. τ = 0%
Proposition 1: The
capital tax rate τ maximizing long run workers’ welfare is τ = 0%
>>> this is the theoretical basis for
the “zero capital tax is socially optimal” result
>>> this result requires three strong
assumptions: infinite elasticity of capital supply; perfect capital markets;
and linear capital taxation
2. Model with capitalists vs middle
class: progressive capital taxation
Now assume we have ktB>0.
I.e. all dynasties accumulate capital and save according to the dynastic,
infinite-horizon utility function.
The
important point is that convergence in individual wealth levels does not
necessarily occur in a such a model. In fact, any wealth distribution such that
the average wealth is equal to k* (the “golden rule” capital stock) can be a
long-run steady-state.
Proposition
(i)
λkA∞ +
(1-λ)kB∞ = k*
(with k* such that f’(k*)=r*=θ)
Consider now
the effects of progressive taxation. Assume that individual capital stocks are
taxed each period at a marginal tax rate τ>0 above some capital stock
threshold kτ .[1]
I.e., the tax is equal to 0 if k<kτ , and the tax is equal
to τ(k-kτ) if k>kτ . Further assume
that the threshold kτ is larger than the “golden rule” capital
stock k* (defined by f’(k*)= r*=θ). One can easily show that the only long
run effect of this progressive capital tax is to truncate the distribution of
wealth. That is, the long run
distribution of wealth must be such that kA∞ < kτ
, but long run average wealth is unchanged (it is still equal to the “golden
rule” level k*). Note that this truncation result holds no matter how small the
tax rate τ : τ just needs to be strictly positive (say, τ =
0,0001%), and one gets the result according to which individual wealth levels
above the threshold kτ must completely disappear in the long
run. This illustrates how extreme the dynastic model really is.
Proposition
3. With progressive capital taxation at rate τ>0 levied on capital
stocks above some threshold kτ (with kτ >
k*), then all long-run steady-state wealth distributions (kA∞
, kB∞) (kA∞ >
kB∞) are characterized by the following two conditions:
(ii)
λkA∞ +
(1-λ)kB∞ = k*
(with k* such that f’(k*)=r*=θ)
(iii)
kB∞ < kA∞
< kτ
Proof : In
steady-state, after-tax interest rates faced by both types of dynasties must be
equal to the rate of time preference. This implies that both types of dynasties
must be in the same tax bracket in the long run: either kB∞
< kA∞ < kτ , or kτ
< kB∞ < kA∞ .
Assume that kτ < kB∞ < kA∞
, and note k∞ the average long run capital stock (k∞ = λkA∞ +
(1-λ)kB∞ ). The long run before-tax interest
rate r∞ is given by r∞
= f’(k∞), and the long run after-tax interest rate (1-τ)r∞
faced by both types of dynasties is such that (1-τ)r∞ =
θ. But kτ > k* implies that k∞ > k*
, which in turn implies that r∞ = f’(k∞) <
r* = f’(k*) = θ , which leads to a contradiction. Therefore kB∞
< kA∞ < kτ . This implies
that the tax does not bind in the long run and that r∞ =
θ and k∞ = k*, in the same way as in the absence of tax.
CQFD.
>>> even with infinitely elastic
capital supply and perfect capital markets, there is scope for progressive
capital taxation: as long as some lower wealth individuals can accumulate
capital and compensate for the higher wealth individuals’ desaccumulation,
progressive capital taxation entails no efficiency cost
[1] A similar result
applies if one replaces the progressive capital tax by a progressive tax on
capital income.